inputs into the production process
- labor, capital & materials
amount of time needed to make all production inputs variable
Average production function
FORMULA: F(L)/L
- output/labor input
output per unit of a particular input
marginal product
FORMULA: derivative of the average product of labor - (change in output)/(change in labor input)
- delta F(L)/ delta L
additional output produced as an input is increased by one unit
C. L1;L2
- when comparing the slope of F at L1 and L2. The slope at L1 is steeper, so MP is higher at L1.
when other inputs are fixed, as the use of an input increases, the resulting additional output will eventually decrease; applies to short run
Practice problem: in the graph, between labor input levels L1 and L2
- marginal product of labor is higher when labor input level is ___.
- average product of labor is higher when labor input level is ___.
what happens to marginal product?
C; Need to observe if the slope of the total product curve is eventually decreasing
why is the law of diminishing marginal return reasonable?
a curve showing all possible combinations of inputs that yield the same output
- mathematically, an isoquant is all combinations (L,K) such that F(L,K) = q
Example: which of the following production curve satisfies the law of diminishing marginal return?
economic: The maximal amount of input (K) that can be reduced when one extra unit of another input (L) is used, so that output remains constant.
Graphical: absolute value of the slope of an isoquant
the isoquants are smooth curves that bend in towards the origin
- the production function satisfies the assumption of diminishing MRTS
- when more and more labor and less and less capital are used in production, it is more and more difficult to use additional labor to replace capital
- perfect substitutes in production (perfectly linear lines)
- perfect complements in production (right angles)
situation in which output more than doubles when all inputs are doubled; allows specialization
F(2L,2K) > 2F(L,K)
situation in which output less than doubles when all inputs are doubled; difficulties in managing effective communication
F(2L,2K) < 2F(L,K)
C(q) = 10 + 4q^2
C(q) = FC(q) + VC(q)
cost of fix input. Does not vary
ex: FC(q) = 10
Consider the production function F(L,K) = 2L+3K. Does F satisfy increasing returns to scale?
cost on variable input. Varies when output level changes, VC(q)
ex: VC(q) = 4q^2
consider a production function F(L,K) = LK. Does F satisfy increasing returns to scale?
AFC(q) = FC(q)/q
ex: AFC(q) = 10/q
VC(q)/q
ex: AC(q) = (10+4q^2)/q = 10/q + 4q = AFC(q) + AVC(q)
Fixed cost (FC)
the rate at which total cost changes when output level changes; the incremental cost when output increases by 1
ex: MC(q) = C'(q)
Variable Cost (VC)
C(q) = rK (K = fixed) + wL(q)
- r = rental rate
- rK = cost spent on capital
- wL(q) = cost spent on labor
Average Fixed Cost (AFC)
in the long run, both K (price r) and L (price w) are variable inputs
step 1: find the cost minimizing input bundle to produce q
step 2: take into account prices and compute cost
step 1: MRTS = w/r (isoquant is tangent to isocost)
step 2: F(L,K) = q (can produce q unit of output)
no, more inputs in the long run makes the choice of input more flexible
products of all firms in a market are identical - no firm can raise the price of its product without losing all of its business
How to find the cost minimizing input bundle in the long run?
case 1: when isoquants are smooth curves that bend in towards the origin and cost minimizing input bundle is interior
a firm has no influence over market price and thus takes the price as given
How to find the cost minimizing input bundle in the long run?
Case 2: other cases, use a graph to find the most minimizing input bundle
are there fixed costs in the long run?
downward sloping
product homogeneity
R(q) = pq
- each firm is a price-taker, so market price p is fixed
revenue - total cost
pi (q) = R(q) - C(q)
the rate at which revenue changes when the output changes
what is the demand curve of a perfectly competitive firm
MR(q) = R'(q); the slope of R(q)
what is the market demand curve of a perfectly competitive firm
MR(q) = p
what is revenue like in a perfectly competitive market?
the rate at which profit changes when the output changes
profit formula
pi'(q) = R'(q) - C'(q)
Marginal Revenue - Marginal Cost
marginal revenue
produces a positive amount of output, but suffers from loss
- in the short run, the fixed cost always exists even if no production
this happens when p is between the minimum levels of AC and AVC
what is marginal revenue in a competitive market
there is a profit; when p is higher than the minimum level of AC
marginal profit
the firm's profit-maximizing output level under each market price
- the part of the MC that is weakly above AVC
marginal profit formula
short run profit maximizing rule
the supply curve shifts up
1) increase/decrease of the price of the variable input -> shifts supply curve up/down
2) technology advancements that decreases marginal cost -> shift supply curve down
long run profit maximizing rule
the sum of all individual firm's short run supply curves under each price level
choosing output in the short run exercise
Q(p*) = S(p*); Q and S are market demand and market supply curves
- p* is the equilibrium price
profit in the short run formula
what happens when q*>0, but suffers from a loss?
the net benefit of all producers
Graphically, the producer surplus for a market is the area below the market price and above the market supply curve, between 0 and output Q*.
what happens when q*>0?
what does a firm's short run supply curve graphically describe?
the price of a good has been regulated to be no higher than Pmax, which is below the market-clearing price P0
what does a firm's long run supply curve graphically describe?
what happens when the marginal cost of production for a firm increases?
the price of a good has been regulated to be no lower than P2, which is above the market-clearing price P0
the demand curve facing a seller is flat (perfectly elastic)
a competitive firm's marginal revenue is equal to the market price
MR=P
short run market supply function
- As a monopolist is the sole producer of a product, the demand curve that it faces is the market demand curve, which is downward sloping.
- In this case, a monopolist’s marginal revenue is below the price level.
how to find the competitive equilibrium
choose to sell its output at any point on the downward sloping market demand curve
producer surplus of producing Q* formula
consumer surplus
- charges a higher price than competitive price level,• charges a price higher than marginal cost
- produces less than competitive equilibrium output level
- earns a profit that is higher than the competitive profit level
-leads to a deadweight loss.
charge each consumer his/her willingness to pay/evaluation of the good or service
- the output level becomes efficient, although consumers have no surplus at all
- First-degree price discrimination is usually difficult to find in real life, because it is difficult for the monopolist to know each consumer’s willingness to pay.
price ceiling
- personalize discount for cars
- personalized pricing/discounts for tax services
Examples of quantity discount (second-degree price discrimination) :
- Buy one get one 50% off offer
- Loyalty cards
- Family size snack is usually cheaper
- Group discount
monopoly market
- Hotel rates: weekends vs weekdays
- Economy class and business class
- Coupons
- Pink tax (gender-based price discrimination)• Regular rate vs student rate
what can a monopolist do
a monopolist's long run output decision
how to find solution to a monopolist's profit maximization problem graphically?
monopolist profit formula
price discrimination
examples of first-degree price discrimination
second degree price discrimination
third degree price discrimination
examples of third-degree price discrimination